skip to primary navigation skip to content
 

 

economic history « Top of the Campops: 60 things you didn't know about family, marriage, work, and death since the middle ages

Top of the Campops: 60 things you didn't know about family, marriage, work, and death since the middle ages

Skip to blog menu ▼

Posts Tagged ‘economic history’

Industriousness and precarity: work before the Industrial Revolution

Thursday, May 15th, 2025

Judy Stephenson

The concept of an ‘industrious revolution’—a period when household productivity and consumer demand increased before industrialization, generating surplus for investment in new technology—has been influential since the late 1990s. For economic historians, the measure of industriousness is the number of days people worked per year. For anybody who was paid by the day, annual income was a function of the portion of the day rate that they received, and the number of days that they received it for. How many days people worked per year is therefore of profound importance to understanding preindustrial living standards, as well as economic growth.  

How many days did people work per year? 

We have surprisingly little information about the number of days people worked in the past. What economic historians know about what people earned in the past has been taken from ‘day wages’, collected since the mid 19th century, from the archives of big institutions. These are mostly for masons, carpenters, bricklayers and their labourers for building work. (It turns out that many of those day wages are labour costs rather than wages.)  

Standard practise in calculating annual wage income is to assume that most people were working nearly all the time; like today’s full-time jobs. For instance, Bob Allen in his seminal work on real wages assumes that the average building and agricultural labourer was working 250 days a year. Greg Clark assumes that the average was 300 days. 

These are high numbers. In the latter case for instance, they imply that more than half of the workforce were working 300 days or more. Since we know that the working week was six days long, a 300-day working year implies that the average worker only missed two weeks of work all year. Just Christmas and Easter? No time off at midsummer? No ‘saint Mondays’ (the early modern equivalent of a duvet day)? No searching for work or odd jobs? 

Marc Chagall, Reclining on the bed.

Even at 250 days a year, the implied level of labour intensity assumes that the average worker was pretty much fully employed. Those retained on annual contracts and apprentices were expected to work all days in the year it must be said, but that was not the predominant proportion of the workforce.  

The most recent research accepts that these assumptions need some qualification. Humphries and Weisdorf (2019) use the price of goods to calculate the number of days work needed to afford a basket of goods as the key to industriousness. However, since wages were sticky or stable in many periods, and prices were not, unsurprisingly this research finds that ordinary workers in the late 17th century and late 18th century (two periods when prices were high) worked over 250 days annually. The implication of this approach is that the standard of living was constant – an assumption which is firmly contradicted by history.   

Although historians understand that the regularity of work was somehow different before the industrial revolution, there has been surprisingly little progress on studying actual work patterns from actual workplaces. There are lots of good reasons for this, the best being that there are not many records. Until production in factories or large workplaces became the norm, most employers did not record the number of working days of their employees, because they paid workers for their output not their labour input. 

Jean-Francois Millet, A stonemason.

Most manufacturing workers and many service workers were paid by the task or by the piece. In this way, the early modern economy was very much like a gig-economy. Only people in construction, shipbuilding, or casual day labouring would have been regularly paid by the day, and it is only at exceptional sites that you can get a full picture of how many people were on site, because the nature of the contracting system was that not all work was accounted for by the day.  

Seasonal patterns

When you do look at actual working records, though, two things become apparent. The first is that working life and production before the industrial revolution was profoundly seasonal. Not much happened in Britain during January and February. Construction site records indicate significant industriousness and high labour intensity on projects until the end of December, followed by a period of quiet in January and early February, where particularly on building projects only the most essential tasks were done, largely for lack of light.  

Many other trades also show a seasonal slowing of trade and business at this time, as transport by roads and waterways was made more difficult due to colder weather conditions. Hence the proverb “Candlemas day, put beans in the clay; put candles and candlesticks away”, as people urged a fresh start after a dark January to prepare to sow beans and work in the new light.   

James Patrick, Sunset on Snow. East Dunbartonshire Council.

Building records from the 18th century often indicate that it was early March before you might see a full team back on site. Some of the best records we have are from the rebuilding of St Paul’s Cathedral. Over the decade 1700-1710 at St Paul’s, one key mason contractor’s team worked on average about 45 percent fewer days in January, February and March than in June, July and August. The cathedral’s own labourers worked half the days in January they did in July.  

In agricultural work, too, the important rest and maintenance time of the dark months gave way to high work intensity in spring. At the docks there was less to unload and pass on, the seasonality of most trade’s shipping being profound. In shipbuilding the numbers of men on site would increase by a third or more from one end of the year to another.  

Precarity

The second observation is that most preindustrial workers did not have a ‘steady’ job. Work was often precarious – much like zero hours contracts today. Building workers moved from site to site, and were not permanently retained by employers. It could take time to find the next job. In textiles, spinners, weavers and knitters worked to order and had to allow time to get materials and supplies from their employers, and time to bring in their work and have it measured and weighed and accounted for. The amounts they worked for orders varied.  

Mark Senior, The Flax Spinners, Rotterdam. The Hepworth Wakefield.

In mining it seems to have been expected that hewers and heavers did not work every day. In potteries and foundries, the working week included much preparation time worked less intensely (on Mondays and Tuesdays) with hours adapted to the demand of customers, with shorter stints worked in times of depression and overtime in time of high demand.  

Of course, the existence of overtime indicates that sometimes people worked more than six days a week. The Royal dockyards are a classic example of this. Overtime and double stints paid high wages when times were good – or war was declared. But at other times, servants and non-regular men were laid off for months at a time.

It is also notable that even when a workplace operated six days a week it was unusual for all workers to work all six days, or get paid for them. At the potteries, the average was between five and six days, and analysis of building site records show that often many people were on site for three to four days a week.  

Conclusion

Only if a full working week was sustained by everyone, without any search costs of looking for other work or moving between sites and employers, could the average number of days worked in a year be above 250 in a workplace. And of course, the early factories, like those of Richard Arkwright, or Benjamin Gott, offered working conditions that encouraged and supported such full-time work – and, in fact, required it. That a labour force unused to such time discipline was not always willing to work to this regularity, is well established.  

Men at work inside a plate glass factory, 1747. Wellcome Collection.

The case for an industrious revolution before regularised factory work is therefore a bit shaky. It certainly seems to be the case that in order to afford new goods or to maintain a standard of living, workers had to work more, but records tell us that precarious employment is nothing new, and work was uncertain and badly paid for many. 

Further reading

  • Allen, R. C., ‘Prices and wages in SE England’. https://www.nuffield.ox.ac.uk/people/sites/allen-research-pages/ 
  • Allen, R., and Weisdorf, J., ‘Was there an ‘industrious revolution’ before the industrial revolution? An empirical exercise for England, c. 1300—1830’. The Economic History Review 64:3 (2011), 715-729. 
  • Baugh, D. A., British naval administration in the age of Walpole (Princeton University Press, 2015). 
  • Burnette, J., ‘Seasonal Patterns of Agricultural Day-Labour at Eight English Farms, 1835–1844’, in Hatcher and Stephenson (eds.) Seven Centuries of Unreal Wages (London, Palgrave, 2018).  
  • Boulton, J., ‘Economy of time? Wedding days and the working week in the past’, Local Population Studies 43 (1989), 28-46 
  • De Vries, J., The industrious revolution: Consumer behavior and the household economy, 1650 to the present (Cambridge, 2008). 
  • Humphries, J., and Weisdorf, J., ‘Unreal wages? Real income and economic growth in England, 1260–1850’. The Economic Journal 129:623 (2019), 2867-2887. 
  • Lipson, E., The history of the woollen and worsted industries (Psychology Press, 1965). 
  • Riley, J., ‘Sickness in an early modern workplace’. Continuity and Change 2:3 (1987), 363-385.  
  • Stephenson, J.Z., ‘Real’ wages? Contractors, workers, and pay in London building trades, 1650–1800’. Economic History Review 71:1 (2018), 106-132. 
  • Stephenson, J. Z., ‘Working days in a London construction team in the eighteenth century: evidence from St Paul’s Cathedral’. The Economic History Review 73:2 (2020), 409-430. 
  • Thompson, E., ‘Time, Work-Discipline, And Industrial Capitalism’. Past and Present 38:1 (1967), 56-97. 
JOIN OUR NEWSLETTER
And get notified everytime we publish a new blog post.

The rise of coal

Thursday, May 1st, 2025

Paul Warde

In the 19th century , no-one doubted the significance of Britain’s use of coal in underpinning its economic and political power – foreign neighbours envied Britain’s resources and mining industry long before the term ‘Industrial Revolution’ came into widespread use. In more recent decades, understanding about how burning fossil fuels has led to climate change puts a new complexion on this epochal shift. It is not only associated with bursting the constraints of the organic economy, but also bringing new hazards on a global scale. What happened in Britain takes on a new significance. 

(more…)

The growth of the service sector

Thursday, January 16th, 2025

Leigh Shaw-Taylor 

The service sector, also known as the tertiary sector, comprises all workers not making a physical product. This includes shopkeepers, wholesalers, publicans, hotel workers, people working in financial services, health and social care workers, professional services, and transport workers. 

The UK economy today, like that of all rich countries, is dominated by the service or tertiary sector. According to the 2021 census, fully 76 percent of the labour force is now in the tertiary sector. But when did the service sector become dominant, and when did it begin to grow? Many people think the growth of the service sector is a recent phenomenon, starting perhaps in the 1950s and picking up speed as Britain de-industrialised from the 1970s. However, new long-run data on male occupations collected by the Occupational Structure of Britain c.1379-1911 project tell a different story. 

(more…)

Was the economy backward before the Industrial Revolution?

Thursday, December 5th, 2024

Leigh Shaw-Taylor

It is widely assumed that before the Industrial Revolution most people worked in agriculture, and that the economy was underdeveloped or backward. But was this really so? The first of these assumptions will be taken up in next week’s blog, while today’s blog will focus primarily on the second.  

(more…)

To the manor bound: Serfdom in Europe

Thursday, November 21st, 2024

Tracy Dennison

Serfdom is usually associated with the medieval period, and conjures images of an impoverished peasantry toiling under duress in the fields around the lord’s castle. This view is not so much incorrect as incomplete. In many parts of Europe, especially central and eastern Europe, there were still enserfed peasants in the 18th and 19th centuries. Serfdom disappeared from the European landscape gradually: first in England, in the decades after the Black Death, and last in Russia, by state decree in 1861.  

(more…)

Three score and ten?

Thursday, August 15th, 2024

Romola Davenport & Jim Oeppen

Campop’s studies of mortality suggest that, in England, average life expectancy at birth varied between 35 and 40 years in the centuries between 1600 and 1800It is a common misconception that, when life expectancy was so low, there must have been very few old peopleIn fact, the most common age for adult deaths was around 70 years, in line with the Biblical three score years and ten. So what does life expectancy actually measure?

(more…)

Women have always worked – for pay

Thursday, August 8th, 2024

Amy Erickson

It is commonly assumed that women entered the workforce in significant numbers only after the World Wars of the 20th century. While women may have been occupied with household duties in previous centuries, the assumption goes, they were much less likely than men to engage in paid labour. This blog explains why a) that’s wrong, and b) the issue is much more complicated than simply a progressive increase in women earning their own salary. 

(more…)

« Home
  • Recent posts

  • Pages

  • Archive

  • Tags

  • age at marriage agricultural revolution childbirth coal demographic transition demography doctors economic history energy English peasants extended family family history family size family tree famine fertility fossil fuels genealogies households illegitimacy industrial revolution marriage maternal mortality medieval medieval history middle ages migration mortality naming practices non-marital fertility occupational structure occupations old age old people organic economy poor laws population size service social history surnames urbanisation women's employment women's history women's wages women's work