skip to primary navigation skip to content
 

 

work « Top of the Campops: 60 things you didn't know about family, marriage, work, and death since the middle ages

Top of the Campops: 60 things you didn't know about family, marriage, work, and death since the middle ages

Skip to blog menu ▼

Posts Tagged ‘work’

The struggle to define self-employment

Thursday, June 5th, 2025

Bob Bennett

Distinguishing someone who is self-employed from another who is waged seems at first obvious: one works for themselves, the other works for others. However, the distinction was often far from simple in the past, and today has been politically contested.  

The differences between employment and self-employment are important for demographic analysis, potentially affecting risk and legally who is responsible for hazards at work. It is important for economic analysis because it reflects different levels of agency or freedom and the dynamics of many businesses. It may be a critical influence on income: a very few who are self-employed may get astonishingly rich. It is also important for understanding motivation, possible levels of self-fulfilment, and how different people respond to changing demands and opportunities in an economy. This all has important historical and policy implications. 

Photo by Dominik Bednarz on Unsplash.

Modern discussions often focus on agency work and zero-hour contracts: is someone self-employed, or are they de facto employed by a business contracting them and giving minimal security? Should this be regulated by government? How should trade unions be involved? How should laws balance between people’s wish for flexible working, and for employers’ response to workforce needs that can fluctuate widely from day to day or week to week? 

The Employment Rights Bill considered by the UK parliament in 2025 is attempting to define and enforce the differences between self-employment and being waged. Its discussion in Parliament and outside demonstrates the current difficulties of definitions, but these are of long standing. 

When did the distinction become important? 

Historically there was freedom between contractors and employers to determine how they would be classified – as self-employed or employees. Arrangements were flexible and often ambiguous. The main force that began to change things was income tax.   

In Britain, income taxes on profits of trade and farming began in 1798, but only became continuous in 1842. Mostly those liable were clearly defined by the nature of their trade, and while the tax rate remained low it was not worth much effort to challenge it. Difficulties began when taxes on wages, which were minor at the outset, were widened in the late 19th century. It then became increasingly necessary to distinguish between waged and self-employed. However, this was initially fairly simple because only ‘salaries’ were taxed (generally affecting only higher earners). 

Arthur Whinnom, Pay Day. Woodhorn Museum.

Major difficulties emerged during and after WW1, when tax rates rose rapidly and the rate of tax on profits became considerably lower than that on wages. When an additional tax on payroll (NICs) was expanded after 1948, this taxed employees even higher than the self-employed. The spiral intensified as governments often favoured increasing NICs on payrolls rather than income tax rates as they were less politically visible. These changes resulted in a 100-year long shift of incentives for people to define their income as self-employment wherever possible.  

During the 1980s and 1990s, the numbers of self-employed increased for structural reasons, but a major element of growth was purely driven by ‘tax efficiency’ – that is, people who claimed they were self-employed when the justification was at best marginal or even bogus. 

Inevitably, tax collectors were keen to limit this effect. The most concerted attack was the IR35 rule introduced in 2000. This set a specific test: that having a regular single or main employer meant you were an employee, even if you were a one-person company. To be self-employed you had to be working on different contracts for different people, with independent negotiation of your prices and costs, whether you were a company or not. This test was up to individuals and had little effect. But in 2017 the test was shifted to public sector employers to determine liability. Employers were also made responsible for collection and any errors in definition (as for other employees through PAYE). This responsibility was extended to private sector employers in 2021.  

There was a ‘flight to safety’. A small reduction occurred of self-employed numbers in 2018, but there were large reductions from 2022. Many of the remaining own account proprietors contracted to large organisations moved to ‘umbrella’ agencies that administer their incomes. In the Figure 1 (below) it is difficult to separate this effect from the Covid pandemic, but most of the 2021-2 reduction is estimated to be the effect of the change in IR35 rule. Highly-paid celebrities who had claimed to be self-employed though working for a media company or the BBC made a lot of noise about their loss of self-employment. However, at the other extreme, many poorly rewarded agency staff were incorrectly classified as employed. The 2025 Employment Rights Bill attempts to tighten these definitions further. 

Figure 1. Self-employment in England and Wales 1994-2024. Source: LFS. [Discontinuities in data definitions over early years have been smoothed].

The ‘gig economy’ 

The ability for online platforms using Apps to connect suppliers of services with consumers has challenged some of the old regulations. Celebrated recent legal cases in Britain have had to define self-employment in light of these new circumstances. However, although the technology may be new, the decisions are almost identical to long-standing distinctions. 

For example, Uber in London was found by the Supreme Court in 2021 to be an employer. Their cab drivers were not self-employed; the contract for hire was between the passenger and company, not between the passenger and the cabbie despite them ordering through an App 

The fine distinctions are clear from Deliveroo, where the Supreme Court found it was not an employer in 2023. In that case, the rider had freedom to accept or reject jobs and could do jobs for others. This may change under the 2025 legislation in parliament. 

Historical examples

The building industry is well-known for the difficulties of definitions. In the past, as now, the smallest and most numerous group of self-employed were jobbing builders: own account and small partnerships that employed only themselves or a small workforce. Most were single tradesmen such as bricklayers, joiners and carpenters or masons. Many larger firms employed these individuals and small partnerships on large jobs. Were the small sole proprietors then employed, or self-employed? 

Firms varied. The largest contractors for railways, canals and dock construction usually hired all navvies and most other workers for the life of the project, and had few permanent staff. In contrast, even the largest ‘master builders’ responsible for constructing churches, public buildings and factories mostly had a core permanently employed workforce of skilled craftsmen and foremen. When needed they employed labourers and a few extra self-employed craftsmen as extras. These workers might continue to be self-employed or be put on the employer’s payroll.  

One way to examine definitions is to look at pay ledgers. Detailed accounting in building firms for personnel attributed to each contract was used to calculate tenders, monitor works, and negotiate any extras needed on completed works. Ledgers were often divided into salaries for foremen, clerks, managers and senior staff, and wages for tradesmen. For John Mowlem & Co. in the 1880s, almost all people were on continuous pay ledgers; only lightermen, carters and extras on piece-work were recorded as self-employed 

Dock Workers, Dundee. University of Dundee, Duncan of Jordanstone College Collection.

Franchises and ‘tied’ activities 

Pubs, inns and beer houses were often owned or tenanted by those who operated them, making them a nationwide source of self-employment, often important for women. Some pubs were tied to breweries who appointed waged managers, but until the late 19th century many tied pubs were tenancies run by the proprietor, with the tie only restricting the drink sold. Most innkeepers were self-employed. 

Some tied pubs were an early form of franchise. Franchises have become a very common business model in modern times. Much depends on the franchise contract as to whether they are sources of self-employment. Most modern fast-food chains and retailers rarely qualify as run by the self-employed. They are de facto branches, though there may be incentives with wages linked to size of turnover. 

Martha Matilda Harper is often credited as creating the first franchise model. Through domestic service she saved enough to open a hairdressers and began selling hair products, especially shampoo. Her business expanded by opening branches where she selected and trained other women using her brand. She had over 500 shops operating across the USA by late the 19th century; but their staff were de facto her employees. 

Isaac Singer’s Sewing Machine Company licenced the rights to sell its machines through agents who were charged a fee. Initially operating in the USA, the business expanded rapidly and by 1867 opened a factory in Glasgow, expanding to 60,000 sales per year by 1880 using about 300 offices in Britain, with numerous agents selling the machines.  

The Prudential used almost entirely an agent model to sell insurance policies: ‘the man from the Pru collected from the door. Founded in 1848 and incorporated in 1861, it had 10,600 agents by 1888 and 18,000 by 1902. Theoretically they could be self-employed, and initially many were also agents for other businesses. But in 1875 almost all were full-time working only for the Pru as de facto employees. The Pru’s district offices were almost entirely concerned with managing the agents. 

Worker-contractors and outwork  

Worker-contractors and outworkers highlight the problematic distinctions between self-employed and workers. Outworkers generally operate at home. Some could exercise a lot of control over the amount of work they took in, whether it was from one or multiple sources, and had some level of control over prices. Under these criteria they could argue they were self-employed. However, independence required not only motivation but realistic opportunities to trade independently. The majority of outworkers had no opportunities to exercise controls, and may not have wished to do so, preferring the security of a fixed price per piece or contract if the employer was viewed as fair. 

One manufacturer locally viewed as fair and having no history of disputes was Daniel Gurteen & Sons of Haverhill, Suffolk, a clothing, towelling, rug and hosiery manufacturer. In 1888 they had a major works with some 1,500 workers, two-thirds female. Additionally another 1,500 or so did work at their homes in the villages around. They had a fixed rate and their work was checked and managed. Old men with donkey carts took out and fetched back the work. Not only did these locals have little motive to trade independently, but Gurteens in any case monopolised most contracting opportunities.

Self-employment in 19th century Britain was not just about the trade or the person’s motives and desires for independence. It was also about where they were, and the scope their town offered to run an independent business. 

National statistics

In the 1891 Census, for the first time, everyone who was economically active was supposed to identify as either a worker, employer, or working on own account. Combining the last two of these categories should give us a count of all ‘self-employed’; everyone else who was economically active was a worker. 

Unfortunately, various defects in the wording and design of the 1891 census, and also its administration, make the resulting information difficult to use. The question was re-designed in 1901. The fundamentals of the census question then continued until the modern censuses, though in almost all censuses the challenges of definition of self-employment make the responses problematic in detail.  

The 1901 census question.

It is notable that the census did not define an employer of domestic servants as an employer: these employers were not counted in census number, yet domestics were counted as employees – resulting in difficulties of balancing estimates of national self-employment rates. 

As a result of this and other difficulties of census design, most modern economic analysis has used the Labour Force Survey (LFS) in preference to the census. This was introduced in the 1970s. However, even this has suffered major problems, and since the 2010s has had severely declining response rates. The Bank of England and others needing an accurate view of self-employment in the economy have been highly critical. In the late 2020s it is planned to introduce a new version of the LFS. Defining self-employment remains a continuing problem! 

Further reading 

Open access 

Paywall 

  •  Bennett, R. J., Smith, H., van Lieshout, C., Montebruno, P., Newton, G., The Age of Entrepreneurship: Business proprietors, self-employment and corporations since 1851 (Routledge, 2019). https://doi.org/10.4324/9781315160375 

JOIN OUR NEWSLETTER
And get notified everytime we publish a new blog post.

Who was self-employed in the past?

Thursday, May 22nd, 2025

Bob Bennett 

It is often assumed that industrial Britain, with its large factories and mines employing thousands of people, left little space for individuals running their own businesses. But not everyone was employed as a worker for others. Some exercised a level of agency operating on their own as business proprietors, even if they were also often very constrained.

(more…)

Industriousness and precarity: work before the Industrial Revolution

Thursday, May 15th, 2025

Judy Stephenson

The concept of an ‘industrious revolution’—a period when household productivity and consumer demand increased before industrialization, generating surplus for investment in new technology—has been influential since the late 1990s. For economic historians, the measure of industriousness is the number of days people worked per year. For anybody who was paid by the day, annual income was a function of the portion of the day rate that they received, and the number of days that they received it for. How many days people worked per year is therefore of profound importance to understanding preindustrial living standards, as well as economic growth.  

(more…)

Did anyone “retire” in the past?

Thursday, April 3rd, 2025

Richard Smith

Could people afford to retire in the past? There is a belief that until widespread retirement became the norm in the second half of the 20th century, men and women were expected to labour until debility or decrepitude made this impossible.  

Attitudes to work in past society 

It is widely assumed that in pre-industrial societies people worked only just enough to fulfil their subsistence needs. This implies that people would work less if their incomes rose, a pattern that economists have termed a ‘backward sloping supply curve of labour’.  

This theory has been challenged by the alternative notion of an ‘industrious revolution’ in the later 17th and 18th century. This revolution, defined by an intensification of hours worked, allowed people to acquire an expanding range of consumer goods.

But neither theory has addressed how these differing circumstances impacted on the working behaviour of older people. 

Sociologists long argued that with a shift away from economies dominated by subsistence agriculture to more economically diversified and increasingly capitalistic labour markets, there would be a negative impact on the labouring lives of the elderly. In increasingly competitive market economies, elderly farmers would be left with unprofitable land, and elderly workers would be pushed out of the labour force. 

Measuring labour force participation of elderly males 

Figure 1 above is based on data from Cardington (Bedfordshire, 1782) and Corfe Castle (Dorset, 1790).  

In neither setting is there any indication that men worked less in their 60s and 70s than earlier in their lives. The data appear to suggest that in the late 18th century the labour force participation rates of elderly males remained close to 80 percent – a level very similar to that found a century later in the 1881 national census. In 1881, older male workers were consistently over-represented in relatively low paid, low status occupations in agriculture, clothing, and general labouring, and underrepresented in high paid and new sectors such as engineering, transport, glass, and electricals.  

Evidence for the three centuries before 1881 shows that the efforts expended by many men in old age to retain a presence in the paid labour force was an enduring feature of their lives.  

Roland Vivian Pitchforth, Old Stone Waller. Manchester Art Gallery.

Older men of all social levels retained a strong preference for self-sufficiency and independence, but those in possession of significant resources could achieve that status most easily. Elite men as they aged were able to sustain well-paid public activities in administration and governance at both local and national levels. For instance, of the 954 English MPs whose ages could be determined between 1754 and 1784, over a third remained in post after age 60, and of those nearly a half only vacated their positions because of death. 

There was an increasing likelihood that poorer men as they aged patched together an ‘economy of makeshifts’ by combining whatever resources and earnings they could gather. This could include pasturage of a cow on the common waste, keeping a pig or poultry, or receiving payment from the overseers of the poor to perform small tasks, such as ridding the parish of vermin or repairing the highway. There was no precise age at which elderly men would cease to engage in these forms of labour. 

Measuring labour force participation of elderly females 

Elderly females also showed little tendency to stop working after age 50, although with some regional variation depending on what work was available. For example, women in their 50s and 60s in Cardington were almost twice as likely to be employed as those of a similar age in Corfe, reflecting the substantial presence of spinning and lacemaking in Cardington. 

George Harvey, Old Spinner. The Stirling Smith Art Gallery & Museum.

An important factor affecting female participation in paid labour was marital status. In Corfe, only 8 per cent of married women over 60 were employed, but 83 percent of elderly widows were listed as in paid employment. In this instance, the loss of a husband would propel women into paid work. In Cardington, women were likely to be in paid employment both during their marriage and in widowhood. Overall, therefore, elderly widows were highly likely to be in some kind of paid employment. 

However, because women’s work was frequently ill-defined, encompassing housework and part-time assistance to their husbands, particularly in agriculture and trades such as inn-keeping and retailing, there may have been under-recording of the extent of their income-generating labour, particularly in old age.  

Elderly working-class women were expected to continue paid work outside and unpaid work inside the household. They were likely to have secured work charring, taking in laundry, and petty trading. Remuneration was minimal, although elderly women were often more successful than old men in finding informal work outside the home. Like men in labouring jobs, low pay for women of lower social status made it difficult for them to accumulate savings.  

John Widdas, An Unidentified Retired Female Servant at Bramham. Leeds Museums and Galleries.

Diaries and correspondence show women in the upper classes actively managing their households and estates. Women from business families and those of the middling sort had opportunities to pursue ventures in later life; many liquidated their late husbands’ assets and loaned cash on interest. A third of elderly female witnesses before London church courts in the 17th and early 18th centuries were maintained by their husband or worked with him, particularly as inn- and shopkeepers.  

Ten percent of those female witnesses who were widowed had a ‘private income’. Fewer than 10 percent are described as ‘supported by their family’, and a further 10 percent were supported in whole or part by the parish. Hence most elderly females relied on themselves or their husbands rather than their wider families or the parish.  

Did the elderly participate in an ‘industrious revolution’? 

On average, witnesses appearing in the Session Papers of the Old Bailey and the Northern Assizes increased their working hours by around 20 percent over the course of the 18th century, although it is not clear if this applied to older people as well as to younger. This intensification of working hours may in part have been driven by a desire to acquire the broadening array of consumer goods including the proliferating colonial groceries of tobacco, tea, coffee, and sugar. Alternatively, the drive to work more days and hours might have been falling wages and rising dependency ratios 

The late 18th and early 19th centuries were characterised by a tightening labour market and an unprecedented expansion of the population entering the work force. Under these conditions, elderly men may have been less able to secure additional hours of paid working time, and it would be hard to characterise any resulting unemployment as voluntary ‘retirement’. 

Funding retirement

How many people stopped work in old age and were able to enjoy a leisured retirement? We have already noted that old age for many was a time when work could not be avoided or abandoned since it was essential as a source of income. Not working might be more a reflection of lack of suitable employment, or perhaps a physical inability to undertake work as the ageing process took its toll.  

However, there were some opportunities to prepare for and guard against the loss of employment at older ages. “Friendly societies” (insurance or savings clubs) grew significantly, and parliamentary returns from 1802-3 record nearly 10,000 such societies with over 700,000 participants. At that time, it was not uncommon to find 40 to 50 percent of the adult male population registered as members of friendly societies in some urban centres. 

However, such societies frequently folded – being of modest size, they often matured with too high a ratio of elderly beneficiaries relative to those of working age paying into them. This would leave the elderly even worse off, having paid into a fund that did not generate any returns. 

By the late 18th century retirement did have a presence, but this was mainly among the elite. There was a growing sense that a pensioned retirement was something deserved following a lifetime of service, especially service to the state. This was first realised among those who had been in the military as well as the civil service. (This was very different to the idea that support in old age was an entitlement for everyone.) 

A Greenwich Pensioner. Wellcome Collection.

Who retired?

Late 19th century Census Enumerator Books (CEBs) of England and Wales differentiate between those described as ‘retired’, those ‘formerly’ in an occupation, and those with ‘pauper’ status. An important study based on CEBs from the West Riding, Cheshire, Glamorgan, Hampshire and Hertfordshire has unearthed some telling patterns of the capacity to retire.  

Overall, men were much more often described as ‘retired’ than women. Regionally, far more males were described as ‘retired’ and far fewer described as ‘paupers’ in Cheshire and West Riding. Here wages were higher and the economies more differentiated, enabling the accumulation of savings and the means to leave work voluntarily.

The overall percentages of old men enumerated as ‘retired’ in the CEBs were more substantial than has been previously assumed. In 1891, over 10 percent of all adult males were enumerated as ‘retired’ in these five counties, and in some registration sub-districts the proportion reached 22 percent.  

Being in an occupation that conferred status, or one based upon property ownership and invested capital, facilitated a voluntary exit from the workforce. Being an army officer, an innkeeper, or farmer meant that one was far more likely to be ‘retired’. There was a notably negative correlation between the proportions of old men listed as ‘retired’ and those receiving poor relief. 

 On the contrary, agricultural and general labourers, domestic servants, laundresses, and charwomen were very likely to be listed as ‘formerly’ in an occupation or as ‘paupers’

British School, An Elderly Garden Labourer. National Trust, Erddig.

Conclusion

The historical evidence does not fully endorse the preference for leisure over labour at any stage in the life cycle, as implied by the theory of the backward bending supply curve of labour. Working until it became physically impossible to do so was the norm.  

However, by the late 18th century, small sections of elderly society were in receipt of pensions that would certainly have enabled them to have lived comfortably without any requirement to work.  

At the same life-cycle stage, circumstances for the labouring poor were very different. There was a noteworthy deterioration in the value of parish welfare allocated to elderly females, as well as reduced employment chances for older men in areas where capitalist agriculture and de-industrialisation predominated. A modestly comfortable withdrawal from labouring in old age was therefore a limited possibility for most, but by no means all, sections of society.  

In 1908 a national non-contributory, but far from generous, old age pension was introduced for all citizens aged 70 and over with an annual income of £21 or less, not in receipt of poor relief and of good character. However, it would not be until the mid-20th century that an adequate nationwide old age pension was in place, and retirement rather than labouring throughout most of an extended old age became the norm. 

Further reading

  • Boyer, G., ‘“Work for their prime: the workhouse for their age”: Old age pauperism in Victorian England’, Social Science History 40 (2016), 3-32. 
  • Heritage, T., ‘The Elderly Populations of England and Wales, 1851-1911: A Comparative Study of Selected Counties’ (University of Southampton, Ph.D. thesis, 2019). https://eprints.soton.ac.uk/444061/
  • Johnson, P., and Falkingham, J., Ageing and Economic Welfare (Sage Publications, London, 1992). 
  • Mathias, P., ‘Time for Work and Play: Relations between Work and Leisure in the Early Modern Period’, Vierteljahrsdchrift für sozial- und Wirtshaftsgeschichte 81 (1994), 305-323. 
  • Saito, O., ‘Who Worked When: Life-Time Profiles of Labour Force Participation in Cardington and Corfe Castle in the Late-Eighteenth Century as Mid-Nineteenth Centuries’, Local Population Studies 22 (1979), 14-29. 
  • Thane, P., Old Age in English History: Past Experiences, Present Issues (Oxford University Press, 2000), chapters, 6, 14 and 19. 
  • Voth, H. J., Time and Work in England 1750-1830 (Oxford University Press, 2000). 
JOIN OUR NEWSLETTER
And get notified everytime we publish a new blog post.
« Home
  • Recent posts

  • Pages

  • Archive

  • Tags

  • age at marriage agricultural revolution census coal demographic transition demography domestic labour economic history English peasants extended family family history family size family tree famine fertility fossil fuels genealogies households industrial revolution marriage maternal mortality medieval medieval history middle ages migration mortality naming practices occupational structure occupations old age old people parish registers poll tax poor laws population size service social history surnames urbanisation wages women's employment women's history women's wages women's work work